Monday, October 14, 2024

Middle East conflict and the global economy

It hasn't happened since the Ukraine conflict erupted in February 2022. It hasn't happened since the Gaza conflict erupted in October 2023?  Will events in the Middle East now derail the global economy? One obvious way they could is by causing oil prices to shoot past the $100 barrel a mark.

Let us see if we can list a few facts:

i. Israel is not interested in a cease-fire in Gaza, much less in a two state solution

ii. Israel thinks it has a good chance of eliminating Hezbollah, the Lebanon-based militia or at least reducing it to a point where it cannot interfere with events in Gaza

iii. Israel also thinks that in order to degrade Hezbollah, it has to deliver damaging blows to Iran

iv. Israel thinks it has the US behind it, wintess the latest US decision to deliver the THAD anti-missile system to Israel and have it manned by American technicians.

The four above mean an escalation in the conflict and a prolonged conflict. Will the oil market remain unscathed in such a scenario? It's not just a matter of enough oil supply being available outside Iran. If Iran's supplies are disrupted, Iran is not going to allow other oil supplies to go through. When Israel attacks Iran, it has to deliver a blow powerful enough to deter Iran from any sort of retaliation. I leave it to military experts to judge if that is possible.

The prospect of an escalation in the Middle East and higher oil prices has obvious implication for the Indian economy. That is the subject of my article in BS, India's economic growth faces two risks and two key challenges.

FINGER ON THE PULSE
T T RAM MOHAN

The finance ministry’s latest Review of the economy, which came out on September 26, exuded confidence about the Indian economy being able to meet the Economic Survey’s growth forecast of 6.5-7 per cent in FY 25. Some two weeks later, the prospect of the forecast being upended by global events is very real. 

Oil prices are hovering around $80 a barrel for Brent crude, an increase of 16 per cent from the September low.  The Indian economy can take the increase in its stride. However, if events in the world at large were to push the price of oil beyond $100, we will have to start worrying.

“Nothing new there,” optimists would argue. “The world has shrugged off worries about oil prices for over 30 months since February 2022, when Russia commenced its military operations in Ukraine.” In June 2022, the price of oil went up to around $120 a barrel. From July 2022 onwards, oil prices have stayed below $100, with prices staying below $80 for the most part.  

Two factors contributed to this remarkable outcome. One, the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (Nato) and the European Union (EU) imposed a price cap of $60 on oil purchased from Russia while also  reducing dependence on oil supplies from Russia. The cap turned out to be quite effective. 

Two, the doctrine of “managed escalation” has played out well. According to this doctrine, Nato would progressively equip Ukraine to effectively fight Russia. Each step on the escalatory ladder would be managed so that Nato itself was not drawn into a direct conflict with Russia. Escalation has been managed,   the war in Ukraine has not derailed the world economy.

The same doctrine has been applied to the conflict between Israel and the Axis of Resistance (comprising Iran and its proxies, such as Hezbollah, Hamas and the Houthis). For over a year now, Israel has been trading fire with Hezbollah on its northern border with Lebanon. These exchanges have been confined to a narrow strip on either side of the border, with casualties on both sides staying within limits. Iran and Israel have engaged in tit-for-tat missile exchanges, inflicting damage that both sides find acceptable. 

“Managed escalation” always carries the risk of miscalculation or error- at some point, one party or both parties can cross tolerable limits. The issue now – and this is where optimists would be mistaken- is not so much miscalculation as cold calculation on Israel’s part. With the successes Israel has had against Hezbollah in recent weeks, Prime Minister Benjamin  Netanyahu believes the time has come to “change the Middle East.” There is the  (prospect?- ok) not only of escalation but of a prolonged campaign.  

A probable Trump victory in November heightens the implied risk. Following Iran’s missile attack on Israel, Mr Trump wants Israel to go after Iran’s nuclear facilities.  While Mr Trump may well be posturing in the run-up to the polls in early November, his known hawkishness on Iran poses clear risks for West Asia and the world economy.

There is another risk that a Trump victory poses, one about which there seems to be less ambiguity. Mr Trump promises sweeping cuts in taxes for corporations as well as individuals, higher tariffs and substantial deregulation. He sees the tax cuts as paying for themselves by boosting growth, but many economists are sceptical. They think the tax cuts will result in wider deficits, an increase in public debt, and slower US growth down the road.  

Mr Trump has promised a tariff of 20 per cent on all imports and a tariff of 60 per cent on Chinese goods. Mr Trump sees higher tariffs not just as protecting US manufacturing but as paying for the tax cuts he has in mind. Economists have raised a howl but many American business leaders think Mr Trump has got it right. Whatever the long-term impact, there is little doubt that Mr Trump’s policies will be disruptive for the world economy in the short term. 

The two risks apply to the world economy as a whole. Apart from these, there are two challenges that are specific to India.

One relates to foreign direct investment (FDI). Net FDI (item 1 in the accompanying table), which is the FDI inflows minus FDI outflows, fell by over $28 billion in 2023-24 compared to 2021-22. The Review says that this is because repatriation of profits (item 4) surged considerably in 2023-24. It says this is not a bad thing because it assures foreign investors of an exit route for profits made in the country. 

However, repatriation of profits is not the only factor dragging down net FDI flows. Gross inflows of FDI (item 3) have fallen steeply from $85 billion in 2021-22 to $71 billion in 2023-24.  The Review argues that FDI flows to emerging markets as a whole have fallen by 15 per cent in 2023 and India is likewise affected. But if India is positioning itself as an alternative to China for FDI, this should not be happening. 

Some analysts contend that the fall in gross FDI has to do with India’s scrapping of bilateral investment treaties that allowed for third-party arbitration of disputes. The change, they say, has made foreign investors nervous. Maybe. Or it may well be that FDI has fallen for the same reasons that private domestic investment has not picked up in recent years. If gross FDI does not rebound strongly in FY25, we would need to be concerned.   

The second challenge, which is relatively short-term in nature, is with respect to foreign institutional investment (FII) flows. FIIs invested $44 billion in India in 2023-24. FII inflows in the April- July quarter of FY25 have fallen to $6.3 billion, from $20.5 billion in the same period of FY24.  Analysts say this is to be expected as Indian stocks are overvalued. There has also been a huge switch of funds to Chinese stocks, given the low valuations in that market. This shift is said to have increased in recent weeks following the stimulus to the Chinese economy. 

A fall in capital flows, combined with oil prices exceeding over $100, is not the best place for the Indian economy to be in. Happily, India’s external position today is strong enough to cope with such a scenario. However, higher oil prices and disruptions in the world economy could   undermine growth projections.  

India has had considerable success over the years in dealing with the sources of instability within the economy. The threats to growth and stability now emanate from outside- geopolitical risks, rising protectionism, and banking instability in the West. 




Thursday, September 26, 2024

Michael Spence has great hopes for AI

Nobel Laureate Michael Spence sees  AI as offsetting two big trends that are working against global growth.

One negative trend is that efficiency or cost has ceased to be the primary consideration in determining the source of supply:

The first is shocks, including war, pandemic, climate change, geopolitical tensions, resurgent nationalism, and growing focus on national security in the conduct of international economic policy. These increasingly severe and frequent disruptions are shifting global supply networks toward greater diversification and resilience. But that is an expensive pressure and a contributor to inflationary pressures.

Another is the fall in productivity growth:

Productivity deserves special attention. US productivity growth averaged 1.68 percent from 1998 to 2007, a period during which many Americans got internet access and, later, mobile phones. Productivity growth then slowed to 0.38 percent from 2010 to 2019.....In Europe, lagging growth and productivity are attributable in part to less rapid and effective adoption and deployment of digital technologies, and to underdeveloped tech sectors relative to the US and China.

These two forces are impacting economies in a number of ways:

The combined effect of these two sets of forces is a relatively rapid shift from demand-constrained to supply-constrained growth. Growth is subdued. Inflation endures. Real interest rates remain elevated. Many economists, including me, believe that the structural conditions I’ve described mean borrowing costs are likely to remain elevated, and certainly higher than during the decade following the global financial crisis.

Spence sees AI as counteracting these two negative forces and leading to a surge in productivity although this will take a long time to happen- he sees the impact no earlier than the towards the end of the present decade:

Of course it will take time. Roy Amara’s law applies here as in past episodes of technological transformation: we tend to overestimate the short-run impacts and underestimate the longer-term ones. My best guess (and it is just a guess, based on current patterns of investment) is that we may start to see meaningful impacts in labor productivity by the end of this decade.

Spence's views are worth noting because economists, in general, remain sceptical as to whether AI will cause productivity to accelerate- they see it as maintaining historical rates of productivity at best.



Saturday, September 21, 2024

Who will regulate the regulators?

Regulators set standards for others. What about the standards at the  Statutory Regulatory Authorities (SRAs) themselves? 

This is one issue that has come to the fore following the current controversy involving the Chairman of SEBI. What are the disclosure standards for the SEBI Chairman? How well are potential conflicts of interest handled? We had news today that SEBI refused to provide the Chairman's list of recusals in response to an RTI query- the news occasioned much outrage in the social media.

K P Krishnan, a former secretary in the finance ministry, has raised the issue of accountability of SRA such as RBI and SEBI in a recent article

The legislative actions of the SRAs are supposed to be subject to legislative scrutiny. The record on this point is disappointing:

Over a 23-year period, between 1999 and 2022, the Lok Sabha parliamentary committee reviewed 13 regulations issued by all SRAs, and the Rajya Sabha parliamentary committee reviewed four such regulations. Sebi alone has issued more than 650 regulations since it came into being. There are more than 20 SRAs at the level of the Union of India, and most of their legislative activity is not being subject to parliamentary scrutiny

There are limits to what parliament can scrutinise. Much responsibility must devolve on the boards of directors of these institutions. Here again, the record is pathetic:

The composition and functioning of the governing boards of all SRAs in India leave much to be desired. They are almost entirely composed of internal persons and serving government functionaries. In practice, the board delegates most of the powers to the chairperson and provides very little oversight. There is a striking gap between the governance standards that Sebi demands of listed companies or the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) demands of banks and  how Sebi and  the RBI themselves are governed.

Krishnan makes two excellent suggestions. One, there must be a separate parliamentary committee to monitor SRAs. Two, the Comptroller and Auditor General (CAG) must undertake performance audits of the SRAs instead of confining itself to financial audits. 

These reforms are necessary. What is missing in SRAs today is democratic accountability, an imperative for any public institution. 


Thursday, September 19, 2024

Fed rate cut : are geopolitical risks irrelevant?

The US Fed's decision to cut the policy rate by 50 basis points is seen as a bold move to head off any incipient tendency towards recession in the US economy. 

I find it bold for a quite different reason. The Fed seems indifferent- or blind- to geopolitical risks. After the pager/walkie-talkie bombing in Lebanon, it appears the Middle East is closer to a full-blown regional war. With NATO inching towards letting Ukraine use longer-range missiles against targets in Russian territory, we seem poised for an escalation in that part of the world too.

So, two major escalations looming with potential repercussions or global inflation and growth.

And yet.... neither the Fed nor the financial markets are taking note!! It is true that we have heard dire warnings about the Ukraine front since February 2022 and the Middle East since October 2023. These warnings haven't come true. It appears all parties to the conflict know how to pull back from the brink. 

That is excellent news but.... can we be sure? The Fed seems more sure than many others.

India's growth prospects: RBI Governor's upbeat assessment

 

The RBI Governor has given a pretty upbeat assessment of India's growth prospects:

India can achieve sustainable economic growth of up to 8% over the medium term, according to the country’s central bank governor.

His comments come shortly after data showed India’s gross domestic product slowed to 6.7% in the second quarter, down from 8.2% when compared to the same period last year. The figures have  ratcheted up pressure on the central bank to launch its own rate-cutting cycle sooner rather than later.

Speaking to CNBC’s Tanvir Gill Friday in an exclusive interview, Reserve Bank of India (RBI) Governor Shaktikanta Das said he expects a growth rate over the next few years of 7.5% for India, “with upside possibilities.”

The Chief Economic Advisor has indicated that a medium-term growth rate of 6.5-7 per cent. Most people make a higher growth rate than that conditional on a slew of reforms. 

If, however, the Indian economy can grow at 7.5 per cent in the coming years on present steam, that would be most reassuring to the government. It certainly changes the fiscal outlook quite a bit. 

Friday, September 13, 2024

Indian banks do have a deposit problem

The RBI has expressed concern about deposit growth lagging credit growth and acting as a constraint on faster growth of credit. One reason, it says, this has happened is because savers, especially young savers, are today more attracted towards alternatives to deposits such as mutual funds and insurance.

Some commentators have said there is no such problem because, first,  invetments in mutual funds and insurance also come back eventually to the banking system as deposits and, secondly, because loans create deposits anyway. They say that if deposits are growing slowly it is because money supply is not growing fast enough.Let the RBI cut interest rates and that will turn on the deposit tap.

I examine these propositions and the fallacies therein in my BS article, RBI's push for deposit growth

Deposits can be retail or wholesale, they can be current account, saving or fixed deposits. Which of these a bank uses for funding loans has implications for its stability. The RBI's exhortations, I argued, are about growing granual retail deposits as distinct from lumpy, wholesale deposits. Not having enough retail deposits to back loans can create serious issues for banks.

FINGER ON THE PULSE

T T Ram Mohan

RBI’s concerns on deposit growth are valid

The RBI governor has urged banks to increase deposit growth. The governor’s exhortations have been met with criticism and even ridicule from some commentators. 

Some analysts contend that the deposit problem is entirely imaginary and that banks do not face any deposit constraint in the matter of making loans. They are wrong. The RBI governor’s concerns are well-founded, as a hard look at the critics’ propositions will make clear. 

                            i.Savers, especially young savers, are turning to alternatives to deposits such as mutual fund and insurance products. That should not worry banks because what is parked with mutual funds and insurance companies returns to the banking system as deposits.

It is true that money invested in mutual funds and insurance products must come back to the banking system. However, when savers invest in banks, they choose saving or fixed deposits with relatively long maturity.  The amounts they invest in mutual funds and insurance companies return to the banking system as current account deposits or fixed deposits of very short maturity. The latter are less stable than saving  deposits. As a result, banks are constrained in the loans they can finance with current account or short-term fixed deposits. More on the importance of the type of deposit later.

              ii.     Loans create deposits, not vice versa. So the idea that deposits can constrain loan growth is plain wrong. 

That loans create deposits is one of the more famous propositions of Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). Its meaning must not be misconstrued. 

A bank can make a loan through an entry in the ledger. The bank then makes a matching entry for deposits on the liability side of its balance sheet. So, yes, the bank can conjure up loans and deposits out of thin air.

However, when the borrower issues a cheque against the loan in order to make a payment, the deposit will need to be backed by funds. For its immediate needs, the bank can borrow funds from the central bank or in the inter-bank market.  

There are limits, regulatory and prudential, to such borrowings. To safeguard its stability, the bank will have to go to the ultimate savers and garner deposits, instead of accessing funds from intermediaries. Again, how loans are funded is material. 

            iii.     Deposit growth is linked to the creation of money by the central bank. It is no use blaming banks for the slow growth of deposits if the central bank is not creating enough money in the first place. 

Money supply is equal to base money (bank reserves plus currency) times the money multiplier. If the central bank wishes to increase the money supply, it can buy bonds from banks through open market operations (OMO), so that bank reserves rise. 

Money supply is also equal to currency plus deposits. When the money supply goes up, deposits on the other side of the equation rise correspondingly. Combining the two equations above, if deposits are not rising fast enough, it is contended, is because the central bank is not creating enough money. 

There are two fallacies in this line of argument. First, central banks cannot be doing OMO and increasing bank reserves just to increase deposits- OMO is done to meet the interest rate target at any point in time.  

Second, we need to be clear about how exactly an increase in reserves contributes to an increase in deposits. When banks have excess reserves, loans can grow faster than otherwise. Incremental loans will be matched by entries of incremental deposits in banks’ balance sheets. So, yes, we will see deposits rise as  money supply expands. 

However, if liquidity and interest rate risks are to be properly managed, incremental deposit entries will have to be backed by stable funds in the form of deposits. 

So much for the criticisms of the RBI governor’s remarks. 

Now to the point about the importance of the type of deposit a bank sources for funding loans..  Deposits can happen through current accounts, saving  accounts, and fixed (or term) deposits (FDs). 

Current accounts carry zero interest and hence are free from interest rate risk. However, as mentioned earlier, current account deposits pose high liquidity risks for banks.  Saving deposits, unlike current accounts, carry an interest cost. The interest rate on saving  deposits is supposed to be considerably lower than on FDs and it fluctuates in a narrow range, so the interest rate risk is also low. If saving  deposits are retail in nature, they are considered highly stable, that is, they pose low liquidity risk.

FDs carry a higher interest rate than both current and savings deposits, but retail FDs are relatively stable compared to corporate FDs (which are typically of shorter maturity). From the point of view of managing liquidity risk, deposits below ~2 crore are considered a preferable form of retail deposits, followed by those below ~5 crore. The exhortations to banks to grow deposits, it must be understood, are about growing retail deposits as distinct from large value wholesale deposits.

That is turning out to be a challenge for many banks. Banks lulled themselves into thinking that they could access retail deposits at a lower cost through online banking and under-invested in their branch networks. They have since woken up to the centrality of the branch network when it comes to accessing deposits. Public sector banks have the legacy of a large network of branches. But they need to rejig their branches, given the rise of new deposit growth centres in the country.

Many private banks offer interest rates close to those of FDs on all savings deposits above a certain minimum. This is a travesty of the concept of saving deposits. Saving  deposits are supposed to offer a low interest rate as banks provide a payment service against them. Because depositors are okay with a low interest rate, saving  deposits will not flee with interest rate changes. 

These features cease to apply if depositors are offered FD-like interest rates on savings deposits. The RBI must mandate that only deposits with an interest rate of up to, say, 150 basis points above the SBI’s savings deposit rate can be categorised as a “saving” deposit. 

Banks have also shot themselves in the foot by over-selling mutual fund and insurance products in order to boost fee income. Little did they realise that this would exact a cost in terms of excessive dependence on bulk deposits to drive loan growth. 

Banks need to remind themselves that loans also bring valuable fee income. They must think through the role of fee-based products such as mutual funds and insurance in the overall scheme of things. The mantra for banking stability remains unchanged: A bank’s focus must be on the core business of getting retail deposits and making loans. 

 


Silicon Valley CEO's high praise for IIT Madras

 Vivek Wadhwa, a successful Silicon Valley entrepreneur, has high praise for IIT Madras in this article:

When I visited IIT Madras earlier this year, I was blown away by the talent, world-class facilities, and their ability to connect with top scientists across India. I was so impressed that I decided to outsource the development of breakthrough technologies for my company, Vionix Biosciences, to them. Frankly, I told my friends and VCs in Silicon Valley where I live, that IIT Madras puts MIT, Duke, Stanford - and the Valley itself - to shame in terms of intellectual capacity, scale, ambition and  readiness to collaborate.

I've been more than amazed by the progress IIT Madras has already made in building technologies that could never be built in the West. The last company that tried to develop what we're doing was Theranos, which burned through $1.4 bn on medical diagnostics that are nowhere near the advanced solutions IIT has already created - at a tiny fraction of the cost.

Wadhwa goes on to make suggestions about the sort of research that Indian educational institutions must focus on:

India must avoid the pitfalls of the US research system, which, despite vast investments in basic research, is often disconnected from real-world applications. The US spends over $130 bn annually on academic research. Yet, much of it remains locked in the 'Valley of Death', where promising research never transitions into marketable solutions. As former dean of engineering at Duke University, Tom Katsouleas had told me, based on his work with the US National Academy of Engineering, 'Only about 1% of university patents are ever commercialised.'

I do not know how IIT Madras evaluates faculty. Do commercial applications carry as much weight in tenure and promotion decisions as publications in journals? If they do, then IIT Madras will find it difficult to improve its ranking in international ratings of institutions of higher education.

But then if research publications alone matter, institutions such as IIT Madras may lose out on applications. Wherein lies the balance between pure research and impact on practice? The answer has implications not just for IITs but also the IIMs and other places. 

Should the IIMs be trying to influence  practice through executive training, consulting and participation in policy-making by using the available research? Or should they try to catch up on research with the top institutions of the world, an objective that will remain elusive in the foreseeable future?
 

Sunday, September 08, 2024

Is Warren Buffett's performance faltering?

That is what this article in the Economist suggests- and it is not the only one.

Berkshire Hathaway, the firm with which Warren Buffett has been famously identified, has underperformed the S&P 500 in the period 2009-23- the firm has produced an average return of 13 per cent per annum compared to the benchmark's 15 per cent. In the period since 2015, it has produced a total return of 155 per cent compared to the benchmark's 164 per cent, as another article points out.  

Before we start dumping on the fabled Sage of Omaha, it is appropriate to place the firm's underperformance in context as the second article cited above does:

The conglomerate's stock has reached a fresh all-time high in 2024, suggesting that, despite the underperformance relative to the S&P 500 since 2015, the company remains a formidable force in the investment world. Furthermore, Buffett's track record since the 1960s, with average annual returns around 20%, speaks to a legacy of success that few can match. The question of whether Warren Buffett has lost his touch is not new; it has arisen periodically throughout his career, only for Buffett and Berkshire Hathaway to emerge stronger.

The Economist article delves into the reasons why performance has been lacklustre in recent years. Size is part of the problem. On a bigger size, sustaining returns is difficult. But then firms such as Apple and Microsoft that are even bigger have managed to do so. An important reason is that the firm is invested in old economy firms and it appears reluctant to bring technological innovation into those, such as using software to let less risky drivers pay lower premiums in its insurance business. 

Mr Buffett chastises boards and management on various counts but his own corporate governance is little to write home about: his firm discloses the bare minimum, has an aged board and does not have an email address or phone number to which questions can be addressed. When you are performing, nobody bothers. When you don't, people start looking closely at these things.

On a different note, Buffett has often been cited as evidence that a forecast of the efficient market hypothesis is incorrect- he is one manager who has outsmarted the index over several decades. I had a post earlier on how Eugene Fama, the father of the hypothesis, still swears by it.

How would Fama explain a phenomenon such as Buffett and Berkshire Hathaway? Fama has said that Buffett is not just an investor. He is somebody who takes over under-performing businesses and runs them. To see whether the efficient market hypothesis holds for entrepreneurs, Fama says he would have take a large cross-section of businesses and evaluate performance- and there isn't that sort of data. 

Fama sees Buffett as picking up individual businesses every few years and improving their returns. When it comes to running a portfolio, Fama says, Buffett himself has recommended that his wife put her money in an index fund! 

Says Fama, "Buffett is my hero". Shows it's hard to get members of the Chicago school to change their minds. 

Maharashtra government offers third option to employees- Revised Pension Scheme!

We had the New Pension Scheme (NPS) in operation since 2004. Before that, we had the Old Pension Scheme (OPS). The central government recently announced Unified Pension Scheme (UPS). The Maharashtra government was quick to announce its acceptance of UPS, giving employees a choice between UPS and NPS. It has since announced a third option, Revised Pension Plan (RPS)!

What's the difference? First, about UPS. Most people think that it's very similar to OPS except that employees have to contribute 10 per cent of their salary whereas OPS required no contribution. Former finance secretary Subhash Chandra Garg has highlighted an important difference. (I too had picked it up but I thought I was wrong). If Garg is wrong, please let me know. 

The UPS, Garg says, assures 50 per cent of the basic pay of the last 12 months of an employee. This will be indexed to inflation. The OPS assured 50 per cent of basic pay plus DA. So the pension amount is not quite the same.  (We do not know whether UPS will be revised with new Pay Commission recommendations as is the case with OPS). However, 50 per cent of basic pay would be an improvement on what most employees have been getting by way of cumulative amount through investment in NPS. 

Now, about RPS. The RPS offered by the Maharashtra government is 50 per cent of the last drawn salary (I presume, again it's the last drawn basic pay). Then, it's clearly superior to UPS? Not quite because the UPS also offers a lump sum amount which, I believe, the RPS does not. For those promoted towards the end, RPS may be better. For others, UPS would seem better.

Garg says it's only a matter of time before government employees begin to clamour for OPS. As the ranks of the government employees post 2004 grows, the clamour will become very difficult to resist. 

Sunday, September 01, 2024

Concentration in the Economics profession

Top researchers in Economics are concentrated in just 8 institutions in the US, an NBER study finds. The study gathered data on the educational and professional affiliations of 6000 award winners of 170 notable winners in three broad areas: natural sciences, enginnering and social sciences. Each of these three areas was broken up into six fields each, giving a total of 18 key fields.

All fields show a declining level of concentration, except Economics which is a clear outlier. Economics shows a high and ascending concentration over time. This is visible in the most notable of awards, the Nobel prize where again Economics shows high concentration whereas chemistry, physics and medicine show low concentration.

The authors examine the reasons why this is so. They hypthesise that three factors are relevant: the dependence on physical equipment, the development stage of a field and the role of prestige. In Economics, physical equipment is not important so researchers are highly mobile, it is a relatively new field and prestige plays a more important role in Economics than in other fields. 

How exactly does prestige matter? Well, the more famous economists receive more citations than academics in other fields. Institutional prestige can be measured by the ranking  of an institution. The top institutions in Economics remained at the top more than in other fields. Consequently, the best names tended to gravitate towards the top institutions, making for more concentration of talent.

Why should we be concerned? The economists at the top institutions control, in a way, publications in the top journals. This means that only ideas that they are comfortable with may get through. In other words, concentration in Economics may mean a monopoly over ideas. New, original and heretical ideas may not find adequate expression. That is bad for the advancement of knowledge.

The more difficult question, which the paper does not address, is: how do we prevent rising concentration in Economics? Part of the answer may be for the non-elite institutions to accept publications in journals other than the top ones for evaluation and tenure. A group of faculty of high calibre, whether from within an institution or from outside, may judge the quality of publications that have not made it to the top three or four publications and give ratings. Institutions may give extra weights to ideas that are outside the mainstream. If the stranglehold over ideas of the top journals wanes, so could the strangehold of the top economists and the institutions they belong to.

Institutions may also give a little more weight for the application of ideas or the impact on practice of academics. Where academics significantly influence policy-making, credit can be given for the purpose of granting tenure. One way or another, it is important that a few institutions do not arrogate to themselves the role of gate-keepers of ideas in Economics.